recent

Tribute to Mac McQuown, GCFP Board Member

Oct 25 Papers

Papers on Financial Policy by Sloan Colleagues

MIT Golub Center for Finance and Policy

Funding pandemic relief: Monetise now

By

Deborah J. Lucas, Sloan Distinguished Professor of Finance and Director, MIT Golub Center for Finance and Policy
Refet A. Gürkaynak, Professor of Economics and Department Chair, Bilkent University

(Reposted with permission from VOXEU)

In advanced economies the current macroeconomic policy scene is dominated by three interrelated challenges: rapidly meeting the unprecedented spending needs to respond to the COVID-19 crisis, holding government debt to a sustainable level, and avoiding deflation. This column argues that  monetizing some of the pandemic-related debt would be the best way to address all three issues simultaneously, even if it risks some future above-target inflation. It proposes a particular mechanism for debt monetization, with the proceeds used to fund the partial replacement of lost wages through the banking system. The proposed mechanism effectively monetizes the cost of the program, in contrast to central banks’ current debt purchase programs, which for the most part have not yet resulted in monetization.  

Massive efforts to support health systems, meet citizens’ subsistence needs, and preserve business establishments in the face of the COVID-19 pandemic have caused government spending in many countries to skyrocket. While there is unusually broad agreement that aggressive fiscal policies are necessary, there is also growing concern over the consequences of the precipitous rise in already high government debt levels that may be slowing the adoption of further beneficial but costly interventions. Meanwhile, the pandemic has exacerbated an existing macroeconomic concern, the risk of continued below-target inflation, or now even disinflation, in the face of sharply curtailed demand.

Economic policymakers therefore face three interrelated challenges: (1) To provide large amounts of debt-funded assistance quickly due to the pandemic; (2) to avoid accumulating unsustainable levels of government debt; and (3) to head off deflationary pressures.

For low-income countries, the first two of these challenges underlie the extraordinary call for a debt service standstill.  For advanced economies, we believe that monetizing a portion of debt created to fund benefits for unemployed or furloughed workers could simultaneously address all three challenges, and that it ultimately would be the least costly and most palatable choice among the available alternatives.

Mechanics of monetization

The sort of program we have in mind would quickly put cash into the pockets of households with diminished incomes and at the same time avoid adding to the public debt. In one version for the U.S., Congress would enact legislation authorizing the Treasury to create special issue bonds to be given to banks, whose value would be credited to individuals’ checking accounts in amounts determined by the program’s rules. To direct the money to where it is most needed, the deposit supplements could be based on a percentage of the individual’s reduction in average paycheck deposits relative to the three months preceding the pandemic, subject to a cap or other limits to ensure progressivity.

The special issue bonds would be zero coupon perpetuities and therefore would not obligate Treasury to any future payments. The legislation would require the Fed to buy these bonds from the banks at par and treat the resulting reserves as non-interest bearing (effectively increasing required reserves by the value of the bonds). The bonds would then remain on the Fed’s balance sheet indefinitely. This monetizes the special issue bonds.

The rationale

This particular mechanism amounts to a directed helicopter drop of money, as also advocated by Gali. The legislative and accounting gymnastics built into our proposal have several important purposes. The first is to put the decision to monetize a portion of emergency spending into the hands of elected officials rather than the monetary authority. That would avoid to the extent possible the perception that the central bank is overstepping its authority by taking fiscal actions, thereby helping it to protect its future independence. The second is to underscore that the policy is in response to a specific and unusually problematic constellation of events, and that debt monetization should not enter the standard toolkit of policymakers. Its more mundane purpose is to ensure that balance sheets of all participants in the transactions in fact remain balanced, and to allow the Federal Reserve to monetize the debt without having to report a negative book equity position, which we believe would cause no real problem but could be more controversial.  

A similar approach may be just as useful in the euro area, where fiscal authorities are still debating area-wide fiscal policies and joint funding mechanisms. Creating pan-euro-area zero coupon perpetuities for purchase by the ECB may meet less resistance than would common borrowing, although recent rulings by German courts suggest there would be questions about the legality of such measures. Importantly, the same three factors are apparent in the euro area as well: the pandemic is devastating livelihoods and economic activity, public debt is a problem, and inflation has persistently been below target.

Government debt monetization has been taboo for a long time, and for good reason. It has too often led to epochs of dangerously high inflation that once set into motion were destructive and hard to stop. However, at this juncture almost all advanced economies are persistently missing their inflation targets from below.

If inflation were to rise above the target by a small margin for a while as a result of the proposed policy, we expect that many central banks will quietly (or vocally) welcome it. And if inflation and inflation expectations begin to climb too much, then central bankers have an array of standard policy tools to combat it. Small amounts of excessive inflation can be dealt with opportunistically, letting the next recession drag on a bit longer. And if the policy were to trigger a more serious rise in inflation than we anticipate, a more costly but effective alternative is to create a recession as a monetary policy choice, as in the Volcker recession.

The question then, is whether it is better to incur a higher human and economic cost of the pandemic by not intervening forcefully now for fear of incurring too much debt; or to take more aggressive fiscal action now, monetize some of its cost while inflation is below target, and risk having to fight some unwanted inflation in the future. To us, the answer seems clear.  

Understanding monetization

Most advanced economies have resorted to leaning on central banks one way or another to accommodate their emergency spending needs, leading to a fear of monetization. We argue that what has been done so far is not monetization, but that to address the current emergency some strictly controlled monetization is in fact desirable.

In general, monetization occurs when a government funds its expenditures by issuing intrinsically worthless claims that the public is compelled to accept, effectively printing paper money. In our proposal, the special issue zero coupon perpetuities issued by Treasury and purchased by the Federal Reserve are doing exactly that. By contrast, issuing government debt in the open market creates an obligation for future repayments of value equal to that of the money raised; it is clearly not monetization. 

Where it gets trickier is when a government’s debt is purchased by its own central bank. The critical question is whether, and by how much, the central bank’s purchases directly reduce the value of claims by the public on the government.[1] In the case of traditional open market operations there is generally no doubt that the government’s obligation to repay the debt has not been materially altered. This is reflected in standard measures of “debt held by the public” that include the government debt held on central banks’ books.

The policy of quantitative easing (QE) employed during the Great Recession that followed the 2007-8 financial crisis massively increased the holdings of government debt on central bank balance sheets. However, like open market operations, those purchases did not in themselves extinguish government liabilities. With QE, central banks purchased government bonds in the open market, paid for with interest-bearing reserves. Banks voluntarily continue to hold those excess reserves as assets. The net effect of QE on the balance sheet of the public thus far appears to have been an equal value exchange: government debt for interest bearing central bank reserves.[2] The flip side is that the consolidated liabilities of the government to the public–the sum of those of the central bank and the fiscal authority—also remained unchanged.

Indeed, many central banks, including the Federal Reserve and the ECB, are purchasing large amounts of government debt, but so far those actions have been akin to QE. Since early March of this year, the Federal Reserve’s holding of Treasury securities has expanded by about $1.5 trillion, paid for by issuing interest-bearing reserves. Those purchases are providing liquidity to the Treasury market and helping to support bond prices, but at this point they are not monetizing the debt. The Bank of England (BoE) is allowing HM Treasury to run an overdraft account, but it hasn’t forgiven the obligation to repay.

Although not there yet, over time these policies may evolve towards monetization. If the Parliament were to pass a law that forgives HM Treasury’s debt to BoE, that debt will be monetized. Otherwise the expansion of the BoE balance sheet will reverse when the overdraft is repaid. Similarly, if the government bonds held by many advanced economy central banks are eventually sold back to the public,  there will be a corresponding decline in outstanding reserve balances and the debt will ultimately be paid with tax revenues. However, if a government selectively defaults on its debt held by its central bank (assuming it legally can) or if its central bank is forced to roll over that debt forever, it will effectively be monetized. Note the use of “forced.” Under the mandate to maintain price stability, central banks would choose to sell debt back to the public were inflation to rise above target. Preventing such eventual sales would require a legislative change to central bank charters or some other mechanism to compel cooperation with the fiscal authority.

Hence, current central bank debt purchases, similar to those made in the aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis, are not monetizing debt. That fact helps explain the low levels of inflation that have accompanied the enormous expansion of central bank balance sheets. Only with an increase in non-interest bearing reserves, unaccompanied by a corresponding increases in the value of future claims on government revenues, can a government obtain fiscal resources without adding to its liabilities. This is monetization, and this is what we are proposing should be done in a limited way during these extraordinary times.

Endnotes

[1] This is separate from pecuniary externalities of monetary policy, such as treasuries being able to borrow at lower interest rates when policy is expansionary.

[2] Reserves being interest bearing due to interest on excess reserves makes it easier to see this but what really matters is that this is a swap of two liabilities of equal value, reserves for debt. The analysis would not have been different in the absence of IOER.

References

Baldwin, R and B Weder di Mauro (2020), Mitigating the COVID Economic Crisis: Act Fast and Do Whatever It Takes, a VoxEU.org eBook, CEPR Press.

Blanchard, O and J Pisani-Ferry (2020), “Monetisation: Do not panic”, VoxEU.org, 10 April.

Bolton, P, L Buchheit , P-O Gourinchas, M Gulati, C-T Hsieh, U Panizza and B Weder di Mauro (2020), “Necessity is the mother of invention: How to implement a comprehensive debt standstill for COVID-19 in low- and middle-income countries”, VoxEU.org, 21 April.

Galí, J (2020), “Helicopter money: The time is now”, VoxEU.org, 17 March.